Back then, the EU had recognized that the complexities of contracts required regulation to be decentralized, relying on those closest to each case. However, the new DMA reverts to broad, top-down rules – a method the Commission appeared to abandon a quarter of a century ago. So why change tact?
One reason is that digital platforms connect various user groups, offer services, and monetize user data and these strong network effects and economies of scale can tilt competition in favor of a dominant platform. However, this “tipping” risk is reduced by users engaging with multiple platforms (called multi-homing) and market segmentation.
For instance, digital advertisers still compete with print media, and niche dating apps like Grindr and J-Date still challenge larger platforms. While network effects and proprietary data can disadvantage such smaller competitors, dominance and abuse must be clearly defined, and markets properly assessed before making any assumptions.
America offers a case in point. US antitrust guidelines clarify that having market power, even a monopoly, from a superior product or business acumen doesn’t violate the law. Refusing to share assets is seen as exclusionary, but legitimate. In contrast, the EU with its DMA now considers refusal to share as potentially raising antitrust issues.
Indeed, the EU’s old “as efficient competitor” test asked if a dominant firm could survive its own exclusionary practices. Now, with the DMA, this test extends to “not yet efficient competitors”, undermining first-mover advantages and redefining competition as cooperation to help weaker rivals.
Nearly 25 years ago, the Commission restructured EU competition policy around three key pillars: clear legal standards, stronger ex-post control, and corporate self-assessment. The DMA lacks all three and should, in my view, be revised.